Executive Order 6102

Inflation, the negative rate of profit, and the Fascist State (Part four)

Jehu Featured Leave a Comment

Executive Order 6102

In the bare bones sketch of Marx’s theory I argued that the value of the object serving as money played no role in its function as money. This was incomplete, of course, but it served to advance my argument until I could directly address the implication of debasement of money by the industrial powers during the Great Depression. In reality, the price (actually value/price) mechanism can only perform its function to coordinate the separate acts of millions of individual labor times if it shares with commodities the attribute of being a product of labor itself, and, for this reason, requires a definite socially necessary labor time for its own production. Because gold has value, it can express the value of the commodities with which it is exchanged.

On the surface, a commodity is exchanged for money, and this transaction is the exchange of two absolutely unlike objects: the money serves no purpose but means of exchange, while the commodity with which it is exchanged is eventually consumed; the money never leaves circulation, while the commodity disappears; the money can always find a new owner, while the commodity only finds an new owner where it is needed. They are as different as night and day. Although, the flows of money through the community are only a necessary reflex of the flows of commodities through the community as it engages in a more or less developed act of social production. But, by always being exchangeable for commodities throughout the community, always being in constant circulation within the community, and by serving only as means of exchange, money brings millions of isolated individual acts of production into some sort of rough coordination.

As the physical expression of socially necessary labor time money is a natural and spontaneous means by which the value/price mechanism regulates the activities of the community in absence of the community’s own planned management. However, I must emphasize, money is only the expression of socially necessary labor time; it is not and should not be mistaken for socially necessary labor time itself. And, it can only express the socially necessary labor time of society, because the community requires some definite socially necessary labor time to create it. What object serves as money for the community is, therefore, of general interest to the whole of the community, and has a very long history — most of which, since we take this history as our starting point, is of no interest to us here. I only note that since this General Interest must take some form, the form it takes during the period under discussion, from the Great Depression until the present, are the laws of the various States regarding the legal definition of money.

Breakdown of the law of value emergence of the Fascist State

On April 5, 1933, the Roosevelt administration issued Executive Order 6102. The Wikipedia outlines the scope of this executive order:

Executive Order 6102 is an Executive Order signed on April 5, 1933, by U.S. President Franklin D. Roosevelt “forbidding the Hoarding of Gold Coin, Gold Bullion, and Gold Certificates” by U.S. citizens. The bank panics of Feb/March 1933 and foreign exchange movements were in danger of exhausting the Federal Reserve holdings of gold. Executive Order 6102 required U.S. citizens to deliver on or before May 1, 1933, all but a small amount of gold coin, gold bullion, and gold certificates owned by them to the Federal Reserve, in exchange for $20.67 per troy ounce. Under the Trading With the Enemy Act of October 6, 1917, as amended on March 9, 1933, violation of the order was punishable by fine up to $10,000 ($167,700 if adjusted for inflation as of 2010) or up to ten years in prison, or both.

This simple executive order, which was succeeded by several additional orders during 1933, and by the Gold Reserve Act of 1934, removed gold as the standard for the dollar, made it illegal to own more than a small amount of the metal, and compelled individuals under penalty of law to turn their gold over to the Federal Reserve in return for the then existing exchange rate of $20.67. On the surface this order just gave the State monopoly over the ownership of gold and reduced money to just a State-issued token. While this step was, in and of itself, fairly staggering, particularly when we consider that it was duplicated in all the big industrial nations at the same time, once we consider the full ramifications of the orders and succeeding law in terms of the various national economies, it quickly becomes apparent that a state monopoly over the ownership of gold, and the replacement of gold standard money by State-issued currency was only the most obvious effect. John Maynard Keynes, who examined the issue entirely from the standpoint of a bourgeois economist, had some inkling of the far reaching implication of State issued ex nihilo money. Fifteen years earlier, he argued that the inflationary consequences of excessive money printing amount to the confiscation of private property:

… By a continuing process of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens. By this method they not only confiscate, but they confiscate arbitrarily; and, while the process impoverishes many, it actually enriches some. The sight of this arbitrary rearrangement of riches strikes not only at security but [also] at confidence in the equity of the existing distribution of wealth.

Those to whom the system brings windfalls, beyond their deserts and even beyond their expectations or desires, become “profiteers,” who are the object of the hatred of the bourgeoisie, whom the inflationism has impoverished, not less than of the proletariat. As the inflation proceeds and the real value of the currency fluctuates wildly from month to month, all permanent relations between debtors and creditors, which form the ultimate foundation of capitalism, become so utterly disordered as to be almost meaningless; and the process of wealth-getting degenerates into a gamble and a lottery.

Lenin was certainly right. There is no subtler, no surer means of overturning the existing basis of society than to debauch the currency. The process engages all the hidden forces of economic law on the side of destruction, and does it in a manner which not one man in a million is able to diagnose.

If excessive money printing raised the question of secret confiscation of property, the actual confiscation of gold, and the replacement of gold money by state-issued currency amounted to the explicit expropriation of monetary wealth. Yet, even this implied expropriation of social wealth in its capitalistic form was not the most significant implication of the state action: From the standpoint of Marx’s theory, the debasement of money was the abolition of the historically developed natural and spontaneously created value/price mechanism as the regulator of the social act of production. In place of a natural relation between the values of commodities and the prices of commodities, the relation between the two was, after this, to be established as a matter of state policy. This separation is the absolute development of the historical antithesis between the commodity and money, since paper money has no use except as medium of circulation of commodities — as means of exchange. Moreover, by this executive order severing gold from money, we see not only that the value of the commodity was severed from its price, but, further, that production was severed from consumption; labor power was severed from wages; surplus value was severed from profits. Finally, with the law of value no longer determining the social necessity of a given expenditure of labor time, the labor time expended by society was no longer limited by social necessity.

In place of the historical, spontaneous and naturally developed mode by which the separate activities of millions of members of Civil Society in every country had been hitherto regulated, social labor and its duration was now regulated by the State, and under conditions determined solely by the State. The abolition of the gold standard did not simply sever the connection between gold and money, and abolish the value/price mechanism, it also placed the total social capital of Civil Society at the disposal of the State — or, what is the same thing, announced the emergence of the Fascist State. Property, the classical thinkers argued, is the power to dispose of the labor of others, hence this total social capital was converted into the property of the State.

The Fascist State as regulator of production and consumption

The entire social capital of every nation was expropriated, precisely as Marx predicted, but in a fashion and under circumstances quite different than those which might have been welcomed by him. As I argued in another post, Marx’s differences with Bakunin came down to difference over whether the Proletariat would be compelled to effect management of social production according to the principle of “to each according to his work”, that is by replacing the existing Civil Society and the State with new rules enforcing labor equally on all members of society. Marx was not making this argument in a vacuum; his theory predicted a breakdown of the law of value as the regulating principle of social labor before the necessary conditions were established for a fully communist society. Society would be required by this breakdown to step in and manage social labor directly and according to a plan. Marx’s argument with the Anarchists essentially asked the question, “By what rules would this management be effected?” As is obvious from an investigation of history, this question was settled decisively in favor of the existing Civil Society, which rose to manage its General Interest — i.e., its interests as a mode of Capital — through the machinery of the Fascist State.

Within ten years of this act, more than 80 million people were dead and the Eurasian continent lay in ruins, as each nation state, finding itself in total control of the productive capacity of their respective nations, immediately put this productive capacity to good use by trying to devour their neighbors — unleashing a catastrophe on mankind. By 1971, with the collapse of the Bretton Wood agreement, a single fascist state, the United States, had imposed on the survivors the very same control over the other national economies, that it imposed on its own citizens.

As I stated in the previous post:

However, there are so many holes in the economist’s definition of inflation, as a matter of due diligence I must consider inflation from the standpoint of Marx’s labor theory of value. If I arrive at the same conclusions about inflation that are expressed in the Wikipedia definition — or at conclusions that throw no new light on the subject — then I will have spent about five hours pursuing a dead end.

I have now considered inflation from the standpoint of Marx’s labor theory of value and have come to decidedly different conclusions than those drawn in the Wikipedia entry on the subject. These conclusions, I argue, suggest a catastrophic breakdown of the conditions of capitalist production and exchange during the Great Depression; and, based on this, the assumption by the State of direct management of social production, the conversion of the total social capital into the property of the State — not by means of outright seizure of this capital, but by taking control of the conditions of exchange — and the extension of this relationship to the entire World Market.

With the assumption of management of social production by the Fascist State, the law of value, which served to limit the average price of the commodity to the socially necessary labor time required for its production, no longer imposed such limits on prices. Hence, prices could be determined by factors other than the value of these commodities. On the other hand, with the law of value — that is socially necessary labor time — no longer imposing a limit on the total labor time of society, this labor time could be expanded in a form that is completely superfluous to social necessity. We can, therefore, define inflation as the chronic general rise in the price level resulting from the further extension of hours of labor beyond their socially necessary limit; or, prices held constant, by the reduction of the ratio of socially necessary labor time to the actual hours of labor expended. Finally, we can see that inflation itself is no more than the result of Fascist State policy, which, acting as the social capitalist, seeks the ever greater extension of the working day even as the productive capacity of society reduces the necessary labor time of social labor.

In my next post, I will examine each of these conclusions in turn.

To be continued

Tastings Around Town

Chicago Sun-Times July 27, 2005 | Celeste Busk Roy’s 720 N. State Road A Fish, Fun & Fusion Wine Dinner begins at 6:30 p.m. Tuesday. The dinner, which will feature wines from Moet Hennessy U.S.A., is being held to celebrate the release of Chef Roy Yamaguchi’s new cookbook Roy’s Fish & Seafood: Recipes from the Pacific Rim (Ten Speed Press, $35). Cookbooks also will be available for purchase at the event. this web site lemon drop martini

The cost is $85, plus tax and tip. For reservations or more information, call (312) 787-7599; www.roysrestaurant.com.

Sushisamba Rio 504 N. Wells The restaurant’s Sake & Sushi 101 class will be held from 2 to 4 p.m. Aug. 6. The interactive class will include an informative tasting of five types of sake with food pairings, as well as a guided do-it-yourself sushi-making session. Students will be able to taste test the suggested food pairings, including items such as seviche, tiraditos and tempura.

The cost is $70. For registration, call (312) 595-2300.

Gridley’s Grille of Long Grove 4868 Illinois 83, Long Grove The restaurant has introduced several martini flights to its cocktail menu. For example, a Gridley Flight ($12) features a French Martini, Appletini and Lemon Drop Martini. A Premium Flight ($15) features Prava, Ultimate and Ciroc martinis. A Polish Flight ($12) features Krolewska, Chopin and Poland’s Select.

For more information, call (847) 478-3663.

Viand Bar & Kitchen 155 E. Ontario The July drink special features a delicious FuzziTini, a peach martini served with a side of peach ice cream, priced at $10. Also available is the non-alcoholic peach lemonade for $5. For more information, call (312) 255-8505.

NEW IN BREW * Target and SuperTarget stores in the Chicago area are marketing new Sangria varietals of the Wine Cube and Mini Wine Cube. The Wine Cube holds the equivalent of four bottles of wine and is priced at $15.99. It comes in a number of additional varieties, including Chardonnay, Merlot, Pinot Grigio and a Cabernet/Shiraz blend.

A Mini Wine Cube of white or red Sangria is the equivalent of two bottles of wine. Also offered in Pinot Grigio and a Cabernet/Shiraz blend, the Mini Wine Cube is priced at $9.99 for 1.5 liters. see here lemon drop martini

* A name like Fat Bastard Wines certainly catches one’s eye. The French winery has added its first 2000 Grand Reserve, a 2000 Shiraz and Mourvedre blend to its portfolio. The Grand Reserve has a spicy nose and hints of cinnamon. The intense red-purple colored wine has a palate filled with juicy flavors and spices suggestive of wild herbs found in France.

The suggested retail price is $19.99. It’s available at Sam’s Wines & Spirits and Binny Beverage Depot stores in the Chicago area. The French wine is imported by Click Imports based in Seattle, Wash. For more information, call (800) 859-0689; www.fatbastardwines.com.

Drink up!

For a cool refreshment with a little kick, how about a Long Island Ice Tea? Rob Vopatek, bartender at Marche, 833 W. Randolph, gives this recipe for the restaurant’s Long Island Ice Tea:

In a shaker with ice, add: 11/2 ounces Belvedere Vodka, 11/2 ounces Hendricks Gin, 11/2 ounces Don Julio Blanco Tequila, 11/2 ounces Bacardi Limon Rum and 11/2 ounces Cointreau. Mix ingredients with ice. Top off with sweet and sour mix. Add splash of cola. Shake. Strain shaker ice and pour into a tall cocktail glass with ice. Garnish with lemon. To make the cocktail a Raspberry Long Island Iced Tea, add a splash of Chambord.

The cocktail costs $10. For more information, call (312) 226- 8399.

Patrons of the 10pin Bowling Lounge can unwind with a massage and martini on Monday nights for $15. Here, Joanna Morris gets a chair massage from therapist Todd Ramsour of the Lakeshore Athletic Club. CHART; SEE BELOW.

Celeste Busk

Author: Jehu Eaves
Visit Jehu's Website - Email Jehu
I am a "marxist-in-recovery", which is to say, I am someone trying to recover for myself the essential humanist thought of Karl Marx. I understand his writings as a radical, critical, and determined opposition to all forms of social coercion and "laws" of society, including, but not limited to, Labor, Property and the State -- a decidedly negative critique of present society that offers no vision of what replaces it. My somewhat awkward musings on this can be found at therealmovement.wordpress.com. I am also on Twitter @damn_jehu
JehuInflation, the negative rate of profit, and the Fascist State (Part four)